MasterFeeds: February 2012

Subscribe in a reader Add to Google Reader or Homepage

Feb 22, 2012

EconoMonitor : China's Slowdown

EconoMonitor : China's Slowdown
EconoMonitor : EconoMonitor » China’s Slowdown

Feb 21, 2012

Bob's World: Monetary Anarchy

Bob Janjuah from Nomura always has insightful analysis. Here is an excerpt from Febuarys report:

I am simply stunned that our policymakers seem so one-dimensional, so short-termist, and so utterly bereft of courage or ideas. It now seems obvious that in response to the financial crisis that has been with us for five years and counting, we are being „told‟ to double up on these same policy decisions. The crisis was caused by central bankers mispricing the cost of capital, which forced a misallocation of capital, driven by debt/leverage, which was ultimately exposed as a hideous asset bubble which then collapsed, destroying the lives and livelihoods of tens of millions of relatively innocent people. Well now, if you listen to the latest from Bernanke and Draghi, it seems that the only solution they can offer up is to yet again misprice the cost of capital, in the hope that, yet again, through increased leverage/debt, we are yet again „greedy‟ enough to misallocate capital, which in turn will lead to yet another round of asset bubbles. Such asset bubbles are meant to delude us into believing that we are now „richer‟. When – as they do by definition – these bubbles burst, those who have been suckered in will realise that their „wealth‟ is instead an illusion, which in turn will be replaced by default risk.

Secondly, I have clearly underestimated the 'market's' willingness, nay desperation, to go along with this ultimately ruinous policy path. Personally, I think this is extremely worrying – the number of clients who tell me that they know they are being forced into playing a game that will end in disaster, but who feel they have to play along and who hope they will get out before it turns, is a depressingly familiar old tale. 

Feb 16, 2012

Moody's Weights Ratings Cuts for Major Banks - NYTimes.com

February 16, 2012, 6:21 am

Moody’s Weights Ratings Cuts for Major Banks


LONDON — Moody’s Investors Service has put Goldman Sachs, Morgan Stanley, Deutsche Bank, UBS and more than 100 other financial institutions on notice.

Citing increasingly challenging market conditions, the credit rating agency said it would review its grades for 114 banks based across Europe, as well as eight other financial institutions based elsewhere, including JPMorgan Chase, Bank of America and Nomura.

Moody’s indicated it could cut some credit ratings by as much as three levels as it weighed the risks to the banks’ investment banking models and large capital market exposures.

“The combination of changed operating conditions and increased regulatory requirements and restrictions has diminished these firms’ longer-term profitability and growth prospects,” Moody’s said in the statement, which was released on Wednesday after markets closed in New York.

In a separate statement from London, Moody’s said it was reviewing its ratings for banks based in European countries, including Italy, Spain and Britain. It cited the prolonged euro crisis, concerns about government debt and risks linked to large capital market businesses as reasons.

Banking stocks fell in Europe on Thursday. In London, Barclays shares fell 1.5 percent and HSBC was down 1.2 percent. In Paris, Société Générale, which also released earnings that missed forecasts on Thursday, and Crédit Agricole both fell more than 3 percent.

“The current environment is characterized by disrupted markets and a deteriorating, uncertain economic outlook,” Moody’s said. “In many countries, weakening sovereign creditworthiness is exacerbating these negative characteristics.”

Moody’s said it was reviewing most banks in Italy, Spain, France and Britain. They include Barclays, BNP Paribas and Crédit Agricole. It also cited “fragile funding conditions, wider credit spreads, increased regulatory burdens and more difficult operating conditions” among the reasons for its action.



Moody's Weights Ratings Cuts for Major Banks - NYTimes.com

Share this|
________________________ The MasterBlog

Feb 8, 2012

ECB: Global liquidity and risk appetite: a re-interpretation of the recent crises


Global liquidity and risk appetite: a re-interpretation of the recent crises

Speech by Benoît Cœuré, Member of the Executive Board of the ECB,
at the BIS- ECB Workshop on
Global liquidity and its international repercussions,
Frankfurt am Main, 6 February 2012

1. Introduction [1]

I am delighted to deliver the dinner speech today at this BIS and ECB workshop on global liquidity. Our two institutions have worked closely and extensively on the topic of global liquidity in recent years, notably in the context of Basel-based organisations, such as the Committee on the Global Financial System, so it made sense for us to organise a workshop on this subject. On a more personal note, as a former co-chair of the G20 Sub-Working Group on Global Liquidity Management, I am particularly pleased to see that work is progressing on this important issue.

The global economic and financial crisis in 2007-08 forcefully demonstrated that fluctuations in global liquidity conditions can lead to distortions in asset prices and cross-border capital flows. These distortions contribute to the emergence of bubbles and to financial crises when the bubbles burst. This is not a new story, but a recurrent theme in modern economic history. In this regard the recent financial crisis has not really been exceptional.

Liquidity, no matter how defined, is widely understood to follow cyclical patterns. These patterns feature one important element which is not yet sufficiently appreciated and which I would like to stress today, namely the self-reinforcing interaction between risk appetite and liquidity. This particular interaction ultimately determines the relationship between the official and the overall level of global liquidity. In this connection, I should perhaps add that Claudio Borio and his colleagues at the BIS were among the first to note this self-reinforcing interaction and introduce the concept of the risk-taking channel. [2]

This evening there are several things I’d like to consider: I’ll outline some of the key concepts in global liquidity and also cover liquidity cycles. I’ll talk about the interaction between liquidity and risk appetite in the Asian crisis, and between liquidity and the recent financial crisis. I’ll discuss the relationship between global liquidity and the availability of safe assets, and the impact of the post-Lehman global liquidity cycle on emerging economies. Finally, I’ll explore some of the policy implications.

2. Key concepts in global liquidity

The Landau Report of the CGFS has pointed out that global liquidity has two separate, but interdependent, components. The first component can be labelled as “official liquidity”, and can be defined as “the funding that is unconditionally available to settle claims through monetary authorities” [3]. Official liquidity can be generated through various instruments. Central banks can create it in their domestic currency through regular monetary operations or through emergency liquidity assistance. In addition, authorities can provide official liquidity in foreign currency by selling foreign exchange reserves and through swap lines between central banks.

The other component is private (or private sector) liquidity. Private liquidity is created to a large degree through cross-border operations of banks and other financial institutions, and increasingly within the shadow banking system.

In normal times, private liquidity dominates official liquidity. But private liquidity is highly pro-cyclical and highly endogenous to the conditions that prevail in the global financial system. The inherent endogeneity of private liquidity means that it can easily evaporate in times of financial stress. The pro-cyclicality is documented via the strong interaction of private liquidity and the global risk appetite of financial institutions. Indeed, the global risk appetite is one of the main determinants of the multiplier that links levels of overall liquidity to levels of official liquidity.

Consequently, while only central banks can create official liquidity (the IMF can only mobilise it and reallocate it across countries), for global liquidity cycles to emerge there is no need for new injections of official liquidity. What is needed is that private or official investors reallocate existing liquidity to other market segments. And when viewed in this light, the true driver of liquidity is the underlying set of factors that allows this portfolio reallocation to take place. Let me explain.

3. Relationship between liquidity and recent crises

A glance at the history of global capital flows over the last 20 years suggests that the liquidity cycles that posed a threat to global financial stability originated inboth advanced and emerging economies. Until 1997, Asia drew in almost half of the total capital inflow into developing countries. The economies of South-East Asia, in particular, maintained high interest rates that attracted foreign investors looking for high rates of return. The region received large inflows of money and saw dramatic increases in asset prices. At the same time, the region experienced high growth. This achievement was widely acclaimed as being part of the “Asian economic miracle”.

But the self-reinforcing interaction between risk appetite and liquidity came to the surface here. The surge in capital flows weakened incentives to improve transparency and corporate governance; it also fuelled leverage, pushing up asset prices further, to unsustainable levels. Those prices eventually underwent a correction, causing individuals and companies to default on their obligations.

The shortage of liquidity created by the crisis changed risk sentiment, thereby increasing the global demand for safe assets. With the US dollar still reigning supreme, the United States became a hub for the recycling of the liquidity that was available globally [4]. All of a sudden, capital was flowing uphill, from emerging to advanced economies, a puzzle famously known as the “Lucas paradox”.

Clearly, however, the surge in capital flows to the US was mainly driven by the desire of the official sector in emerging-market and oil-exporting economies to increase their war chests of reserves and insure against global shocks, and not by utility-maximising decisions of their private sector. Nevertheless, those inflows contributed to the decline in long-term interest rates and increased risk appetite in many of the advanced economies. The self-reinforcing interaction between risk appetite and liquidity came back with a vengeance. Of course, one should not neglect the domestic inefficiencies in advanced economies that allowed the financial crisis to occur in the first place. That said, the global dimension of the underlying forces is striking.

The eventual implications of this interaction for the advanced economies were not so different from those for Asia a decade earlier. Again, one saw distorted incentives within the lender-borrower relationship, a highly leveraged economic climate, and upswings in asset prices to unsustainable levels. This resulted in the “Great Recession” and the corresponding fall in global economic activity.

The ensuing sovereign debt crisis in the euro area can be seen – at least to some extent – through the lens of global liquidity and its cycles. In an environment of abundant liquidity and high risk appetite, sovereign yields in the euro area converged at very low levels. Government bond spreads did not reflect differences in macroeconomic fundamentals. This distorted incentives, both in the public and the private sectors. Sovereigns over-borrowed and put off necessary reforms. In some Member States it was the private sector that took on excessive debt, fuelling unsustainable real estate bubbles which, when they burst, pulled the banking system down and then affected public finances. In other words, abundant liquidity undermined market discipline, which could otherwise have become an important pillar of macroeconomic and fiscal discipline in the euro area.

4. Shortage of safe assets and global liquidity

There is also a striking link between the global liquidity cycle and the shortage of safe assets in the global economy. Let me elaborate.

Financial crises, but also economic downturns in general, trigger a rise in global risk aversion. This in turn induces a flight to safety by global investors, resulting in an excess global demand for safe assets. As an illustration, think of the current nominal yield on some short-term sovereign debt, which is close to zero and has even turned negative in some constituencies. The consequent shortage of safe assets globally, however, is a significant impediment to the functioning of the global financial system. How can we, as policy-makers, address this recurrent problem?

First, emerging market economies should develop an efficient financial system and sound legal, regulatory and macroeconomic policy frameworks in order to create safe, globally accepted financial assets.

Second, the euro area needs to regain its role as a global supplier of safe assets. Some investors have doubted whether the sovereign debt issued by some euro area countries can be considered as risk-free. However, by restoring fiscal discipline, euro area sovereign debt will be viewed once again as risk-free. We have made significant progress in the last couple of years, with the establishment of the EFSF, the launching of the ESM, the approval of the six-pack legislation and of the fiscal compact.

Third, the unused resources of the international monetary system need to be mobilised. According to estimates, US government bonds of around USD 2.1 trillion and overall reserves of USD 6.5 trillion [5] are held by emerging market economies. However, standard methods to quantify the optimal level of reserves suggest that the current level of reserves would not be justified purely for precautionary motives. It would be advisable, therefore, to utilise some of these excess reserves to stabilise the international monetary system, while Europe is enhancing its firewall. One obvious way to do this would be via the IMF. The IMF could borrow global excess reserves and use them to support programme countries that are suffering from liquidity shortages, under strict conditionality. Restoring confidence in these economies would in turn stabilise regional debt markets and contribute to the global supply of safe assets.

5. Impact of post-Lehman global liquidity cycle on emerging economies

The outbreak of the global economic and financial crisis led to a speedy and coordinated response by major central banks. They supplied significant amounts of liquidity via different channels, including currency swaps and non-standard measures. In parallel, the IMF and multilateral development banks have been required to expand their balance sheets.

This global response has, however, also initiated a lively discussion among policy-makers about how to address liquidity shortages with instruments providing official liquidity. In particular, there has been increasing demand in policy circles for harmonisation, standardisation and some sort of pre-commitment to provide official liquidity through foreign-currency swap arrangements between central banks.

Let me just remind you, however, that foreign currency swap lines are, to some extent, the international extension of the lender-of-last-resort function of reserve currency- issuing central banks. As the lender-of-last-resort role in the domestic context is subject to the well-known principle of “constructive ambiguity”, there is no reason to believe that a different approach would be warranted in an international context. That said, central banks should aim to improve the current infrastructure for conducting foreign exchange swap arrangements, ensuring that future policy responses face no technical obstacles.

The surge in official liquidity is, however, also associated with the launch of non-standard monetary operations in advanced economies. These policies seek to stabilise the domestic economy and have been criticised by emerging markets’ central banks. Those of you who attended the G20 discussions in 2011 will remember the animated exchanges on this issue. If anything, this confirmed that, for any meaningful discussion of international monetary reform to take place, one needs to better understand the driving factors of global liquidity and its impact on domestic policies. The emerging market participants argue though that unconventional measures taken in developed economies have created excessive global liquidity and that this, in turn, was a key factor behind the massive increase of capital flows into their economies between 2009 and mid-2011. This surge was then widely blamed for the appreciation pressures exerted on their currencies, contributing to a build-up of financial imbalances and asset price bubbles, high credit growth and risks of overheating in those markets.

However, an important question is whether idiosyncratic “pull factors” have influenced the transmission process of official liquidity expansion. Indeed, recent studies argue that there is a significant degree of heterogeneity in the way different emerging economies were affected by US monetary policy [6]. Pull factors, such as country-specific fundamentals and institutional characteristics, are just as important as “push factors” coming from developed economies. For instance, countries with fundamentally undervalued exchange rates are of course prone to surges in capital inflows.

Conclusions

Reinterpreting recent crises through the lens of global liquidity cycles cannot hide the fact that the crises themselves have their origins in more fundamental “fault lines”, to paraphrase Rajan. [7] Liquidity fluctuation and cycles simply exacerbate these underlying weaknesses. For instance, in the Asian crisis, regulation and supervision of the banking system was weak in many instances, as was corporate governance in general. Similarly, the recent financial crisis revealed gaps in regulation and supervision, especially in segments such as the shadow banking system, as well as the lack of a macro-prudential approach to financial supervision. Finally, the debt crisis in the euro area has its roots in insufficient fiscal discipline and, even more importantly, in divergent productivity trends among the Member States. Such divergence sows the seeds of balance-of-payment imbalances and ultimately leads to a sudden stop of capital inflows into peripheral countries. Obviously, adequate policy responses will have to focus primarily on these structural issues.

At the same time, it is essential to adopt measures that can break the self-reinforcing interaction between risk appetite and liquidity in order to avoid further financial crises. Here, I see three avenues that merit further reflection:

  • Micro- and macro-prudential measures – these aim to prevent the build-up of financial fragilities and the emergence of credit and asset price bubbles. This includes of course the liquidity and capital adequacy-related measures which are at the heart of the Basel III accord. This may also include capital management techniques insofar as they are internationally consistent, and insofar as they are not a substitute for fundamental reforms;

  • Further improvements in the financial regulatory framework – these would enable national supervisors and central banks to better monitor and, if necessary, rein in endogenous liquidity creation within the financial sector. This includes the oversight and regulation of the shadow banking system and the implementation of OTC derivatives market reform;

  • Further reflection is also warranted on precautionary foreign-exchange reserve holdings and on international coordination in the face of global liquidity shocks. These deliberations should build on the seminal work done by the CGFS on liquidity arrangements between central banks, and on the progress achieved by the IMF with the creation of the Precautionary and Liquidity Line, in addition to the already existing FCL and PCL.

Progress along these three avenues would help to provide a consistent policy framework for addressing global liquidity.

I thank you for your attention.

European Central Bank
Directorate Communications
Press and Information Division
Kaiserstrasse 29, D-60311 Frankfurt am Main
Tel.: +49 69 1344 7455, Fax: +49 69 1344 7404
Internet: http://www.ecb.europa.eu

Reproduction is permitted provided that the source is acknowledged.


Read the article online here: ECB: Global liquidity and risk appetite: a re-interpretation of the recent crises

Richard Koo balance sheet recessions « Real-World Economics Review Blog

Richard Koo discusses the balance sheet recession phenomena currently engulfing the developed world - USA, EU.

RWER issue 58: Richard Koo « Real-World Economics Review Blog

Share this|
________________________ The MasterBlog

Feb 3, 2012

Spain Orders Banks to Set Aside More Money for Problem Property Assets - NYTimes.com

Spain Orders Banks to Set Aside More Money for Problem Property Assets
NY Times

MADRID — Spanish banks will need to set aside funds to cover billions of euros more in bad property assets under new rules announced Thursday by the country’s economics minister, Luis de Guindos.

The rules, to be adopted by government decree Friday, are the latest effort by the government to require banks to recognize the cost of years of reckless lending during a construction boom that came to an abrupt halt four years ago, with the onset of the financial crisis.

Mr. de Guindos called the additional provisioning of €50 billion, or $65.7 billion, “substantial,” especially given what had been achieved to date. From 2008 to mid-2011, Spanish banks set aside €66 billion for doubtful property assets, he said, even as Spain’s construction sector collapsed.

Over all, Spanish banks have accumulated €323 billion of property assets, of which €175 billion have been labeled “problematic” by the Bank of Spain.

“We are taking an important step toward transparency and toward the health and reinforcement of the banking sector,” Mr. de Guindos said at a news conference.

The new rules are also designed to pave the way for a fresh round of banking mergers, particularly aimed at ailing cajas, or savings banks.

Since the start of the crisis, the number of savings banks has already been cut to 17 from 45. But several of the remaining or merged entities remain troubled, in particular Bankia, which was the result of a seven-way merger led by Caja Madrid and which went public last year in a share offering that raised €3.3 billion.

In recent weeks, speculation has focused on whether CaixaBank could absorb Bankia.

Such a combination would create the largest lender in Spain. But CaixaBank, based in Barcelona, is likely to demand not only control of the combined entity but also significant state guarantees to help it mop up Bankia’s distressed property portfolio.

Until the crisis hit and required the central bank to rescue a handful of cajas, the savings banks had accounted for about half of the Spanish banking sector and had spearheaded the financing for the construction boom, often under the control and guidance of local politicians.

Under the rules presented Thursday, banks will need to set aside funds equivalent to 80 percent of their property assets, compared with 31 percent now.

For housing that is already built, the provisioning requirement climbs to 35 percent from 25 percent.

The new thresholds must be reached at the end of this year for most banks, with an additional year granted for newly merged entities.

The measures come as Spain is bracing for a recession, with the economy expected to contract 1.5 percent and unemployment — already more than double the European average — seen rising further.

Spain’s construction collapse has also been costly for commercial banks, as underlined Thursday by Banco Bilbao Vizcaya Argentaria, which reported a decline of 39.5 percent in net profit from domestic operations last year, to €1.36 billion.

BBVA, the second-largest bank in Spain by assets, after Banco Santander, said its 2011 net profit fell 34.8 percent, to €3 billion, with Mexico overtaking Spain as the market contributing most to earnings.

BBVA also reported its first-ever quarterly loss, of €139 million for the fourth quarter, after a write-down of €1.01 billion relating to its activities in the United States.

Santander this week reported a 35 percent decline in net profit for 2011, to €5.35 billion.

Read the whole article online here: Spain Orders Banks to Set Aside More Money for Problem Property Assets - NYTimes.com

ShareThis


The MasterFeeds

MasterSearch

Categories

MasterFeeds News Finance china money stocks USA Commodities United States debt Gold Venezuela Dollars bonds Markets economics trading Banks FED Hedge funds Asia LatAm Oil default credit metals Mining international relations central_banks CapitalMarkets HFT russia zerohedge Euro Israel Silver democracy India Japan SEC bailout Africa Liberalism Middle East elections insider trading Agriculture Europe FX Iran Tech Trade VC bitcoin copper corruption Brazil CoronaVirus ForEx Gold Silver NYSE WeWork chavez food real estate Arabs EU Facebook France IPO Maduro SWF TARP UN canada goldman government recession revolution war Abu Dhabi Cannabis Capitalism Citigroup Democrats EIA Jobs NASDAQ PDVSA Palestinians Saudi Arabia Softbank Stats Trump Turkey Ukraine demographics ponzi socialism 13F AIG Berkshire Hathaway CBO Cargill Colombia Cryptocurrency ETF Ecuador Emerging Markets Eton Park Google Hamas Hezbollah Housing IMF LME Lebanon Mindich Mongolia NYC OPEC PIIGS Pakistan Paulson Pensions Peru Potash QE Scams Singapore Spain Syria UK Yuan blockchain companies crash cybersecurity data freedom humor islam kleptocracy nuclear propaganda social networks startups terrorism Advertising Airlines Andorra Angola Anti-Israel Apple Automobiles BAC BHP Blackstone COMEX Caracas Coal Communism Crypto DRC DSK Double-Dip EOS Egypt FT Fannie Mae Form Foxconn Freddie GM Gbagbo History ICO Iraq Italy Ivanhoe Ivory Coast JPM Juan Guaido Lava Jato Libya London M+A MasterEnergy Mc Donald's Miami Mugabe Norway Norwegian Odebrecht Oyo PA PPT Palantir Panama Politics QE2 Republicans Rio Ron Paul ShengNu Soleimani South Africa Tokens Tunisia UN Watch UNESCO UNHRC Uber VW Wyclef anti-semitism apparel bang dae-ho cash censorship chile clothing coffee cotton derivatives emplyment foreclosures frontrunning haiti infrastructure labor levi's mortgages philosophy shipping social media treasury women